Institutions

Stable orbits in human systems



Our collective neurosocial operating system, for running distributed processes on our distributed hardware.

Douglass North, Elinor Ostrom, Daron Acemoglu, Ronald Coase and colleagues, broadly construed.

What are the effects of the social arrangements we construct for ourselves? We tend to talk openly about constructing or intervening in a limited subset of these, say “a robust free press”, and “competitive markets”. Our lives are, however, the site of intersections of a whole swag of co-evolved systems; manners, notions of honour, legal systems, clientilism, slavery, freedoms, states (democratic or otherwise), property rights, religions… These systems have different degrees of legibility. For all that it is not clear how to measure these things, it is clear that they make huge differences to our society and how it works… Variation across the globe is also suggestive that they are contingent; The world you grew up in is not the only possible one. (Unless you are Francis Fukuyama circa 2000).

I’ll probably file social capital, whatever that is, here, since whatever use the term does reliably seem to have is about institutional function. An important class of institutions that keep on popping up are ones for management of commons so I slice off a chunk of this page for that.

  • Henry Farrell, Why Coases’s penguin didn’t fly:

    Coase wanted to explain why we saw firms at all, given the benefits of market exchange. Why did we need miniature hierarchies with bosses and subordinates, if we could just buy and sell our services on markets instead?

    His answer was transaction costs. Some transactions are too messy or awkward to be easily handled by putting out to the marketplace. Those are the transactions that are handled in-house through hierarchy. Other transactions, which are more straightforward, can be contracted for with outside providers, through market processes. Finally (although he doesn’t really discuss this) the balance can change over time, as new technologies emerge that make transactions more or less easy to carry out through hierarchy or markets.

    This is a powerful insight, which provided a platform for the work of Oliver Williamson and many other organizational economists, as well as Benkler. Yet it has buried within it a crucial assumption — that change is driven by efficiencies. […]

    [This highlights] an important problem which isn’t really discussed by Coase, and hence is not discussed by Benkler — power. Power relationships often explain who gets what, and which forms of organization are taken up, and which fall by the wayside. In general, forms of production that are (a) more efficient, but (b) inconvenient or unprofitable for powerful actors, are probably not going to be taken up, since those powerful actors will block them. Yet if one starts from an efficiency perspective, it is very hard to build power relations in, since one believes that change in practices and institutions is not driven by power relations but by efficiency.

    […] if you are an economist, as Coase is, you really ought start from the assumption that individuals are self interested. If self interested actors have the power to block changes that would hurt their self interest, they are going to do so.

  • The Seshat: Global History Databank brings together the most current and comprehensive body of knowledge about human history in one place. Our unique Databank systematically collects what is currently known about the social and political organization of human societies and how civilizations have evolved over time.

  • Why Nations Fail

  • Guy Who Took Job Making Barrels In 1400s Didn’t Mean For That To Become Family’s Identity For Next 25 Generations

  • The Real Development was the Friends We Made Along the Way

Impartial institutions

My term is not quite right, but I also do not like Yudkowsky’s term: Local Validity as a Key to Sanity and Civilization

You can also look at laws as a kind of game theory played with people who might not share your morality at all. Some people take this perspective almost exclusively, at least in their verbal reports. They’ll say, “Well, yes, I’d like it if I could walk into your house and take all your stuff, but I would dislike it even more if you could walk into my house and take my stuff, and that’s why we have laws.” I’m never quite sure how seriously to take the claim that they’d be happy walking into my house and taking my stuff. It seems to me that law enforcement and even social enforcement are simply not effective enough to count for the vast majority of human cooperation, and I have a sense that civilization is free-riding a whole lot on innate altruism… but game theory is certainly a function served by law.

The same way that money is both medium of exchange and store of value, the law is both collective utility function fragment and game theory.

In its function as game theory, the law (ideally) enables people with different utility functions to move from bad Nash equilibria to better Nash equilibria, closer to the Pareto frontier. Instead of mutual defection getting a payoff of (2, 2), both sides pay 0.1 for law enforcement and move to enforced mutual cooperation at (2.9, 2.9).

From this perspective, everything rests on notions like “fairness”, “impartiality”, “equality before the law”, “it doesn’t matter whose ox is being gored.” If the so-called law punishes your defection but lets the other’s defection pass, and this happens systematically enough and often enough, it is in your interest to blow up the current equilibrium if you have a chance.

In economic development

See economic development.

References

Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2001. The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation.” American Economic Review 91 (5): 1369–1401.
———. 2012. The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation: Reply.” The American Economic Review 102 (6): 3077–3110.
Albouy, David Y. 2012. The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation: Comment.” The American Economic Review 102 (6): 3059–76.
Allen, Danielle, Henry Farrell, and Cosma Rohilla Shalizi. 2017. Evolutionary Theory and Endogenous Institutional Change.”
Beale, Nicholas, David G. Rand, Heather Battey, Karen Croxson, Robert M. May, and Martin A. Nowak. 2011. Individual Versus Systemic Risk and the Regulator’s Dilemma.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 108 (31): 12647–52.
Bowles, Samuel. 2004. Microeconomics: Behavior, Institutions, and Evolution. Princeton University Press.
Bowles, Samuel, Jung-Kyoo Choi, and Astrid Hopfensitz. 2003. The Co-Evolution of Individual Behaviors and Social Institutions.” Journal of Theoretical Biology 223 (2): 135–47.
Bowles, Samuel, Alan Kirman, and Rajiv Sethi. 2017. Retrospectives: Friedrich Hayek and the Market Algorithm.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 31 (3): 215–30.
Buchanan, James M. 1954. Social Choice, Democracy, and Free Markets.” Journal of Political Economy 62 (2): 114–23.
Buchanan, James M, and Gordon Tullock. 1962. The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. University of Michigan Press.
Charness, Gary, and Matthias Sutter. 2012. Groups Make Better Self-Interested Decisions.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 26 (3): 157–76.
Conway, Drew. 2010. Networks, Collective Action, and State Formation.” SSRN Scholarly Paper ID 1726041. Rochester, NY: Social Science Research Network.
Crawford, Sue E, and Elinor Ostrom. 1995. “A Grammar of Institutions.” The American Political Science Review 89: 582–600.
Denzau, Arthur T, and Douglass C North. 1994. “Shared Mental Models: Ideologies and Institutions.” Kyklos 47: 357–31.
Dimico, Arcangelo, Alessia Isopi, and Ola Olsson. 2017. Origins of the Sicilian Mafia: The Market for Lemons.” The Journal of Economic History 77 (4): 1083–1115.
Engerman, Stanley L., and Kenneth L. Sokoloff. 2002. Factor Endowments, Inequality, and Paths of Development Among New World Economics.” National Bureau of Economic Research.
Farrell, Henry, and Bruce Schneier. 2018. Common-Knowledge Attacks on Democracy.” SSRN Scholarly Paper ID 3273111. Rochester, NY: Social Science Research Network.
Farrell, Henry, and Cosma Shalizi. 2012. “Cognitive Democracy.” Crooked Timber 23.
———. n.d.a. An Outline of Cognitive Democracy,” 44.
———. n.d.b. “Evolutionary Theory and the Dynamics of Institutional Change,” 41.
Farrell, Henry, and Cosma Rohilla Shalizi. 2021. 9 Pursuing Cognitive Democracy.” In 9 Pursuing Cognitive Democracy, 209–31. University of Chicago Press.
Friedman, David, Peter Leeson, and David Skarbek. 2019. Legal Systems Very Different from Ours. Independently published.
Hayek, Friedrich. 1979a. Law, Legislation and Liberty. Vol. 3. London: Routledge And Kegan Paul Ltd.
———. 1979b. The Political Order of a Free People. London: Routledge And Kegan Paul Ltd.
Hayek, Friedrich A. 1988. The Fatal Conceit: The Errors of Socialism. Vol. 1. Routledge.
———. 1996. Individualism and Economic Order. University Of Chicago Press.
Hofman, André A. 2001. Long Run Economic Development in Latin America in a Comparative Perspective: Proximate and Ultimate Causes.” United Nations Publications.
Karl, Terry Lynn. 2000. Economic Inequality and Democratic Instability.” Journal of Democracy 11 (1): 149–56.
———. 2003. The Vicious Cycle of Inequality in Latin America.” What Justice? Whose Justice? Fighting for Fairness in Latin America, 133–57.
Keith, Robert G. 1971. Encomienda, Hacienda and Corregimiento in Spanish America: A Structural Analysis.” The Hispanic American Historical Review 51 (3): 431–46.
Knight, Jack, and Itai Sened. 1998. Explaining Social Institutions. University of Michigan Press.
Loasby, Brian J. 1999. Knowledge, Institutions, and Evolution in Economics. Routledge.
Lockhart, James. 1969. Encomienda and Hacienda: The Evolution of the Great Estate in the Spanish Indies.” The Hispanic American Historical Review 49 (3): 411–29.
———. 1972. The Social History of Colonial Spanish America: Evolution and Potential.” Latin American Research Review 7 (1): 6–45.
Mesquita, Bruce B de, James D Morrow, Randolph M Siverson, and Alastair Smith. 1999. An Institutional Explanation of the Democratic Peace.” The American Political Science Review 93: 791–807.
Newell, Barry, and Robert Wasson. 2002. “Social System Vs Solar System: Why Policy Makers Need History.” In. Grenoble.
North, Douglass C. 1994. “Economic Performance Through Time.” The American Economic Review 84: 359–68.
North, Douglass C, John Joseph Wallis, and Barry R Weingast. 2009. Violence and Social Orders : A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History. Cambridge ; New York: Cambridge University Press.
O’Kane, Rosemary H. T. 1981. A Probabilistic Approach to the Causes of Coups d’Etat.” British Journal of Political Science 11 (03): 287.
Obstfeld, David. 2017. Getting New Things Done: Networks, Brokerage, and the Assembly of Innovative Action. Stanford, California: Stanford Business Books, an imprint of Stanford University Press.
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action (Political Economy of Institutions and Decisions). Cambridge University Press.
———. 1992. “The Rudiments of a Theory of the Origins, Survival, and Performance of Common Property Institutions.” Making the Commons Work: Theory, Practice and Policy.
———. 1998. A Behavioral Approach to the Rational Choice Theory of Collective Action.” The American Political Science Review 92: 1–22.
———. 2000. Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 14: 137–58.
Ostrom, Elinor, Joanna Burger, Christopher B Field, Richard B Norgaard, and David Policansky. 1999. Revisiting the Commons: Local Lessons, Global Challenges.” Science 284: 278–82.
Przeworski, Adam. 2004. The Last Instance: Are Institutions the Primary Cause of Economic Development? European Journal of Sociology 45 (02): 165–88.
Putnam. 1993. The Prosperous Community: Social Capital and Public Life.” The American Prospect 13: 65–78.
Putnam, Leonardi, and Nanetti. 1993. “Social Capital and Institutional Success.” In Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton University Press Princeton, NJ.
Rodrik, Dani, Arvind Subramanian, and Francesco Trebbi. 2004. Institutions Rule: The Primacy of Institutions Over Geography and Integration in Economic Development.” Journal of Economic Growth 9 (2): 131–65.
Schlager, Edella, and Elinor Ostrom. 1992. Property-Rights Regimes and Natural Resources: A Conceptual Analysis.” Land Economics 68: 249–62.
Sokoloff, Kenneth L., and Stanley L. Engerman. 2000. History Lessons: Institutions, Factors Endowments, and Paths of Development in the New World.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 14 (3): 217–32.
Svendsen, Gert Tinggaard. 2018. Trust.
Tocqueville, Alexis de. 1840. Democracy in America.
Tooby, John, Leda Cosmides, and Michael E. Price. 2006. Cognitive Adaptations Forn-Person Exchange: The Evolutionary Roots of Organizational Behavior.” Managerial and Decision Economics 27 (2-3): 103–29.
Valentine, Melissa A, Daniela Retelny, Alexandra To, Negar Rahmati, Tulsee Doshi, and Michael S Bernstein. 2017. Flash Organizations: Crowdsourcing Complex Work by Structuring Crowds As Organizations.” In Proceedings of the 2017 CHI Conference on Human Factors in Computing Systems, 3523–37. ACM.
Zingales, Luigi. 2000. In Search of New Foundations.” The Journal of Finance 55 (4): 1623–53.
———. 2017. Towards a Political Theory of the Firm.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 31 (3): 113–30.

No comments yet. Why not leave one?

GitHub-flavored Markdown & a sane subset of HTML is supported.