Soft incentive mechanism design

Markets, cakes, karma, and reverse game theory, applied to humans

September 22, 2014 — June 29, 2022

bounded compute
economics
faster pussycat
game theory
incentive mechanisms
institutions
networks

Mechanism design for the moral wetware of human beings. In practice that means we might relax some of the mathematical axiomatisation and consider more qualitative/fuzzy ways of thinking about it that are more “inspired by” formal algorithmic/game-theoretic models than presuming exactness. What do our rarefied abstract models of mechanisms imply for societies at large?

Sometimes, sometimes I also pretend to be even fuzzier than I claim, because I notice that for many people thinking about how we might design incentive systems to be moral has a flavour of taboo. Observationally, I can get more buy-in talking about “fair systems” that do their best to circumlocute around their own rationale. I find this latter type of fuzziness uncomfortably disingenuous but maybe this is ust a case of sensitive terminology and I should not get stuck on that on the way to making substantive differences.

Figure 1: A mechanism incentivising coordination.

“Reverse” game theory, bargaining, auctions, pie slicing, swarm sensing for autonomous agents. Reputation mechanisms. Voting systems are mechanisms, and the Arrow impossibility theoryem and Gibber-Satterthwaite theorem are foundational results in mechanism design. The classic, assassination markets, are no longer at the vanguard according to Brian Merchant, but prediction markets are a classic incentive mechanism for distributing forecasts (Merchant 2020). Every blockchain-style cryptowhatsit is a mechanism design problem. More important for this notebook, better governance is a mechanism design problem.

Surprisingly widely applicable; for example, one might frame generative adversarial learning as an ingenious mechanism design.

Also, I feel like this is a situation where the alternative to explicit mechanism design seems to be bad implicit mechanism design. Or, maybe, a misunderstanding of mechanism.

1 Examples

  • Condorcet Internet Voting Service

  • Choron is a case study in designing a mechanism for handling house chores.

  • robovote:

    RoboVote is a free service that helps users combine their preferences or opinions into optimal decisions. To do so, RoboVote employs state-of-the-art voting methods developed in artificial intelligence research. […]

    For subjective preferences, the approach is known as implicit utilitarian voting. We assume that each participant has a (subjective) utility function that assigns an exact utility to each alternative. Our goal is to choose an outcome that maximizes utilitarian social welfare, which is the total utility assigned to the outcome by all participants. […] we only ask for a ranking of the alternatives. […]

    […] For objective opinions, let us focus first on the case where the desired outcome is a ranking of the alternatives. We assume that there is a true ranking of the alternatives by relative quality, and our goal is to pinpoint a ranking that is as close as possible to the true ranking, given the available information.

2 Iterative conversation games

See iterated conversation games.

3 Quadratic voting

TBD. Is quadratic voting this the same quadratic? Consider public goods provision (Buterin, Hitzig, and Weyl 2019).

Quadratic voting

4 Incoming

  • Facebook will change algorithm to demote “borderline content” that almost violates policies

  • Dàzéxiāng Qǐyì is the name of the perverse incentive uprising during the Qin dynasty

    Chen Sheng and Wu Guang were both army officers who were ordered to lead their bands of commoner soldiers north to participate in the defense of Yuyang (simplified Chinese: 渔阳; traditional Chinese: 漁陽). However, they were stopped halfway in present-day Anhui province by flooding from a severe rainstorm. The harsh Qin laws mandated execution for those who showed up late for government jobs, regardless of the nature of the delay. Figuring that they would rather fight than accept execution, Chen and Wu organized a band of 900 villagers to rebel against the government.

5 References

Akerlof. 1970. The Market for ‘Lemons’: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics.
Arthur. 1994. “Inductive Reasoning and Bounded Rationality: The El Farol Problem.” American Economic Review.
———. 1995. “Complexity in Economic and Financial Markets.” Complexity.
Atanasov, Rescober, Stone, et al. 2015. Distilling the Wisdom of Crowds: Prediction Markets Versus Prediction Polls.” Academy of Management Proceedings.
Aziz, Bouveret, Caragiannis, et al. 2018. Knowledge, Fairness, and Social Constraints.” Proceedings of the AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence.
Aziz, and Brandl. 2012. Existence of Stability in Hedonic Coalition Formation Games.”
Aziz, Brandl, Brandt, et al. 2018. On the Tradeoff Between Efficiency and Strategyproofness.” Games and Economic Behavior.
Aziz, Brandt, and Harrenstein. 2013. Pareto Optimality in Coalition Formation.” In Games and Economic Behavior.
Aziz, Caragiannis, Igarashi, et al. 2021. Fair Allocation of Combinations of Indivisible Goods and Chores.”
Aziz, and de Keijzer. 2011. Complexity of Coalition Structure Generation.”
Aziz, and Rey. 2019. Almost Group Envy-Free Allocation of Indivisible Goods and Chores.”
Berg. 2003. “Normative Behavioral Economics.” The Journal of Socio-Economics.
Bernheim. 2002. “Taxation and Saving.” In Handbook of Public Economics.
Bhattacharya, and Packalen. 2020. Stagnation and Scientific Incentives.” Working Paper 26752.
Bowles, and Gintis. 1998. “Efficient Redistribution: New Rules for Markets, States and Communities.” Recasting Egalitarianism: New Rules for Communities, States and Markets.
Brandt, and Bullinger. 2022. Finding and Recognizing Popular Coalition Structures.” Journal of Artificial Intelligence Research.
Buchanan. 1954. Social Choice, Democracy, and Free Markets.” Journal of Political Economy.
Buterin, Hitzig, and Weyl. 2019. A Flexible Design for Funding Public Goods.” Management Science.
Challet, Marsili, and Zhang. 2000. “Modeling Market Mechanism with Minority Game.” Physica A: Statistical and Theoretical Physics.
Easley, and Kleinberg. 2010. Networks, Crowds, and Markets: Reasoning about a Highly Connected World.
Gasparyan, Gerasimov, Voronov, et al. 2015. Rewarding Peer Reviewers: Maintaining the Integrity of Science Communication.” Journal of Korean Medical Science.
George. 2009. Preference Pollution: How Markets Create the Desires We Dislike.
Gintis. 2010. “The Dynamics of Generalized Market Exchange.”
Graham-Tomasi, Runge, and Hyde. 1986. Foresight and Expectations in Models of Natural Resource Markets.” Land Economics.
Grossman, and Stiglitz. 1980. On the Impossibility of Informationally Efficient Markets.” The American Economic Review.
Hubbard. 2014. How to Measure Anything: Finding the Value of Intangibles in Business.
Hudson, Botzen, Czajkowski, et al. 2014. “Risk Selection and Moral Hazard in Natural Disaster Insurance Markets: Empirical Evidence from Germany and the United States.”
Jackall. 2009. Moral Mazes: The World of Corporate Managers.
Jan. n.d. “Recognition and Reward System for Peer-Reviewers.”
Lo. 2004. The Adaptive Markets Hypothesis.” The Journal of Portfolio Management.
Louzoun, Solomon, Goldenberg, et al. 2003. World-Size Global Markets Lead to Economic Instability.” Artificial Life.
Maital. 1986. Prometheus Rebound: On Welfare-Improving Constraints.” Eastern Economic Journal.
Mann, and Helbing. 2016. Minorities Report: Optimal Incentives for Collective Intelligence.” arXiv:1611.03899 [Cs, Math, Stat].
Merchant. 2020. Click Here to Kill.” Harper’s Magazine.
Merrifield, and Saari. 2009. Telescope Time Without Tears: A Distributed Approach to Peer Review.” Astronomy & Geophysics.
Nordhaus. 2005. Schumpeterian Profits and the Alchemist Fallacy.” SSRN Scholarly Paper ID 820309.
Offer. 2002. Why Has the Public Sector Grown so Large in Market Societies? The Political Economy of Prudence in the UK, c. 1870-2000. Working Paper 44. Oxford Economic and Social History Working Papers.
Padgett, and Powell. 2012. The Emergence of Organizations and Markets.
Paich, and Sterman. 1993. Boom, Bust, and Failures to Learn in Experimental Markets.” Management Science.
Shah. 2022. Challenges, Experiments, and Computational Solutions in Peer Review.” Communications of the ACM.
Simon. 1991. Organizations and Markets.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives.
Spence. 2002. Signaling in Retrospect and the Informational Structure of Markets.” American Economic Review.
Su. 1999. Rental Harmony: Sperner’s Lemma in Fair Division.” The American Mathematical Monthly.
Sun. 2014. To Divide the Rent, Start With a Triangle.” The New York Times.
Sutton. 2001. Technology and Market Structure: Theory and History.
The Economist. 2019. Can Technology Plan Economies and Destroy Democracy?
Valentine, Retelny, To, et al. 2017. Flash Organizations: Crowdsourcing Complex Work by Structuring Crowds As Organizations.” In Proceedings of the 2017 CHI Conference on Human Factors in Computing Systems.
Viljoen, Goldenfein, and McGuigan. 2021. Design Choices: Mechanism Design and Platform Capitalism.” Big Data & Society.
Xiao, Dörfler, and van der Schaar. 2014. Incentive Design in Peer Review: Rating and Repeated Endogenous Matching.” arXiv:1411.2139 [Cs].
Xu, Zhao, and Shi. n.d. “Mechanism Design for Paper Review.”